Strong asset management companies can solve default loan crisis
NPLs do not disappear with time; the problems only grow worse with time unless there is a political will to resolve them
The ability of the monetary policy to influence inflation, credit and ultimately the real economy is a central concern for Bangladesh. Relevant channels are, however, weak and changes in policy rates by the Bangladesh Bank have only limited effect — if at all — on other interest rates and on the economy.
Since Bangladesh is a bank-dependent country, more liquid banks can enhance the impact of monetary policy on credit supply and the real economy. Similarly, financial development can strengthen the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy.
Banks in Bangladesh suffer from high levels of non-performing loans (NPLs), which stood at 9% in June 2022, compared to 8.5% in the previous quarter. One needs to recognise that NPLs weigh on the supply of credit and thus on investment and growth via a number of channels, such as locking in bank capital into unviable projects and unproductive activities, reducing bank profitability, distorting capital allocation, and illegal capital flight.
High NPL levels also impair the monetary transmission mechanism to the real economy.
Furthermore, high NPLs do not remain as problems for the banks alone. The government usually gets involved in a big way especially in the resolution process, such as injection of capital, especially to the failing public sector banks, setting up of asset management companies (AMCs) or other measures.
NPLs also have a significant implication on the fiscal sector through contingent fiscal liabilities, and the government, at times, ends up bailing out the financial institutions through recapitalisation.
But why do banks in Bangladesh accumulate high NPLs? Several factors contribute to the deterioration of the loan quality of banks. Some analysts point to macroeconomic factors such as financial mismanagement; others point to policy lending by the banks usually at the behest of the government; still others find links to weaknesses in bank regulations, poor bank management, corruption, and unscrupulous practices.
The state-owned banks often act as if they are fiscal agencies, providing poor follow-ups once a loan is disbursed. Heavy bank losses usually result from poor quality of assets.
Some studies point to financial liberalisation, lax monetary policy, and capital inflows as factors that contribute to increased liquidity in the economy; increased liquidity, in turn, affects the lending behaviour of banks and encourages them to engage in reckless lending, often leading to asset bubbles, particularly in equity and real estate prices. As a consequence, the bank's crucial role of financial intermediation is hampered.
Effective prudential regulation and supervision of banks are essential to financial stability and efficient operation of the economy because the banking system plays a central role in the payments system and in mobilisation and distribution of savings.
In Bangladesh, although prudential regulations may appear adequate, the implementation is often inconsistent, leading to a moral hazard behaviour by the banking and corporate sectors.
In addition, lack of efficient and functioning insolvency laws or bankruptcy and foreclosure laws to support asset recovery and to deal with timely credit repayment not only accelerate the NPL accumulation process but also set a barrier in the efficient and swift disposition of NPLs. Besides the effects on bank intermediation, factors affecting NPL resolution vary considerably. There are important institutional factors or political will or inherent business cultures that are important determinants.
Several countries have used AMCs to rapidly clean up the books of banks with bad assets. The usual procedure is that banks unload nonperforming assets to an AMC, clean up their books, and continue with its primary role of financial intermediation. The AMCs, either government or private-owned, then dispose of the acquired assets through a variety of means such as public auctions, resale of assets to original borrowers, joint ventures, securitisation, or even running the acquired business themselves.
In terms of the institutional design, six criteria are considered important for an AMC's successful operation: objectives (clear and non-conflicting); management style (e.g. the AMC is willing to consider new operational strategies such as joint ventures); human resources (e.g. sufficient expertise and skills in associated areas); funding availability (e.g. availability of government guarantees or adequate funds relative to the level of bad assets to be disposed); relative portfolio size; and political will (e.g. whether or not the AMC has extrajudicial power to accommodate rapid debt resolution). These are necessary for ensuring efficiency, flexibility and transparency of the AMC.
In general, empirical evidence from several countries suggests that AMCs help expedite the restructuring or resolution of huge stocks of NPLs. They can also be instrumental in stopping the deterioration of banking sector profitability.
However, the design of an AMC has a significant effect on its performance. There appears to be a trend towards establishing private, instead of public or government-funded, AMCs that are strong in management and human resources. The private sector route may be followed through special purpose vehicles (SPVs), which may have less concern about political interference and funding. SPVs are private sector-owned AMCs that normally buy bad assets and dispose of them for profit.
The varied performance of AMCs in different countries shows that the establishment of AMCs is not, by itself, a panacea. There are preconditions and supportive institutional setups that facilitate its operation and render it more effective. An AMC needs to have independence from political interference, sufficient financial resources, adequate pool of experts, and well-focused objectives. Successful AMCs may even be endowed with special legal powers to overcome the complex judicial procedures for asset recovery.
Since high GDP growth can reduce the cost, one policy to resolve NPLs is proper macroeconomic management that facilitates stability and growth. The government also needs to ensure the institutional and legal framework which is conducive to a speedy restructuring and resolution of the assets transferred to the AMCs from banks. The judicial and legal framework for insolvency should be efficient and least time-consuming.
Thus successful AMCs can help banks improve their balance sheet picture, thereby allowing banks to free up capital for lending. On the other hand, for successful restructuring of NPLs into high value uses, a supportive institutional and legal framework of AMCs is crucial. The government may decide to set up special bankruptcy courts to attend to AMC-transferred assets cases only, along with strict time-bound proceedings including the appeal process.
These measures will help increase the prices offered by AMCs to the banks as the residual value of restructured NPL assets will increase; thereby encouraging banks to release the better priced bad loans. The global experience points to one lesson: NPLs do not disappear with time; NPL problems only grow worse with time unless there is a political will to resolve them.
The author is the executive director of the Institute for Inclusive Finance and Development (InM) and can be reached at [email protected]